Friday, August 20, 2010

EM capital markets growth prospects after the global crisis (2010)

The global crisis has further enhanced the relative growth prospects of emerging markets (EM) capital markets. Advanced economies’ capital markets will continue to make up the bulk of global financial assets, developed markets (DM) deleveraging and EM leveraging notwithstanding. Emerging Asia has not only the largest capital markets, but also the most developed markets in the EM space. From the perspective of global investors and, even more so, financial services providers, some (segments) of the rapidly growing EM financial markets can only be accessed with some difficulty and tapping into their growth requires a well-thought-out, focused strategy. This fact notwithstanding, the “opportunity costs” of not building exposure to – or a platform in – the EM will be increasing over time.

The stock of EM financial assets (bonds, bank assets, equities) grew from USD 15 tr in 2002 to USD 29 tr in 2008, after taking into account exchange rate and valuation effects. As a share of global financial assets, EM assets grew from 10% to 16%, while, as a share of global GDP, they rose from 47% to 57%, according to the IMF. The global crisis has further enhanced the relative growth prospects of EM capital markets. The crisis can arguably be interpreted as a Kooan-type “balance sheet recession”. The term originally described companies seeking to minimise debt rather than maximize profits following Japan’s financial bust. Today’s situation is somewhat different in the sense that it is banks and households that suffer from excess leverage and seek to minimise debt, thereby generating extra-low interest rates, weak consumer demand and weak private sector investment. Private-sector deleveraging in the major advanced economies will lead to a significant rise in public debt over the next few years, similar to what happened in Japan after the bust.

Most advanced economies will experience only modest financial asset growth (ex-government debt). While most EMs are “under-leveraged”, many advanced economies are “over-leveraged”. As of 2008, domestic debt (excluding government liabilities) averaged 400% of GDP in the EU and 250% in the US, but only 100% in the EM. Improved economic and financial stability, continued solid economic growth prospects and rapid per-capita growth will drive solid EM asset growth, not only in dollar terms but also as a share of total global assets and global GDP. Add to this the prospect of higher returns on the back of higher underlying growth and improved EM risk relative to the DMs, and it is not difficult to understand why global investors and financial services providers are allocating a larger share of their capital and investment to EMs.

This optimistic-sounding prediction comes with a few caveats, however. First, advanced economies’ capital markets will continue to make up the bulk of global financial assets for the foreseeable future, DM deleveraging and EM leveraging notwithstanding. At present, the G-3 (EU, Japan, US) make up 80% of global financial assets, while the EMs account for slightly more than 15% of the total. To illustrate the same point: EU financial assets are 2.5 times larger than all EM assets combined. By extension, the bulk of capital markets-related revenues remains highly concentrated in the DMs, even if revenue growth is bound to be greater in the EMs.

Second, the bulk of EM assets is concentrated in Emerging Asia. Not only is EM Asia larger in terms of GDP, but the financial-assets-to-GDP ratio is significantly higher than in the other EM regions. This holds true for total financial assets and it is true in each capital markets segment. Both equity market capitalisation and the stock of private-sector bonds are around twice as large as the other EM regions combined. To a large extent, this reflects differences in regional savings rates and macroeconomic stability.

Third, EM capital markets are relatively bank-centred, while private bond markets are quite under-developed, with some notable exceptions (e.g. Korea, Malaysia). Equity markets are relatively large, Eastern Europe excepted. The size of individual market segments does not generally say much about the sophistication and liquidity, nor about the risk-reward prospects. Generally speaking, however, EM Asia is more advanced than the other EM regions, especially as regards local bond, derivatives and equity markets.

International financial services providers and investors seem to be pushing into the EMs in general and Emerging Asia in particular –pulled by EM economic and financial prospects and much-improved financial stability and pushed by less than buoyant DM prospects. However, it is important to bear in mind that EM financial markets are growing from a low base. Some important markets can only be accessed with great difficulty; or foreign financial institutions face more or less extensive restrictions and – and this will become an increasingly important theme – intensifying competition from increasingly sophisticated local financial institutions. These caveats notwithstanding, the EMs, and particularly Emerging Asia, have a huge development and growth potential. Tapping into this growth will not be easy and will undoubtedly require a very focused and well-thought-out strategy. Nonetheless, the potential “opportunity costs” for financial services providers of not creating a solid, focused business platform, and for global investors of not building substantial exposure to the EMs will certainly be increasing over time.

Wednesday, August 4, 2010

Rising Brazil may be passing up an opportunity (2010)

Empirical evidence suggests that savings rise after economic growth takes off. Economic reform and stabilization in Brazil seem to have triggered just such a growth take-off. However, in order for the virtuous cycle to be sustained at an ever higher level of 5% (or more), the government would need to allow domestic savings to rise. Officials frequently point to the significant levels of inequality and poverty and Brazil’s democratic political system in an attempt to rationalize why a reduction in government expenditure is neither desirable nor feasible. A look at India’s experience in the 2000s suggests that this view is overly pessimistic.

Comparing Brazil with European countries, the United States and Japan, countries with vastly higher per capita incomes and mature demographic profiles, President Lula in a recent speech suggested that a high tax burden was necessary to finance public policies. This is debatable. By improving the efficiency of public expenditure, the government could almost certainly afford to reduce both expenditure and taxation without compromising its social and economic objectives. This is critical for if the government fails to rein in current expenditure growth, Brazil will be passing up an opportunity to raise its potential growth rate to 5% (or more).

Empirical evidence suggests that savings typically rise after economic growth takes off. In other words, the causality runs from higher growth to higher savings, allowing for a permanently higher level of investment, rather than the other way around. This begs the question of what ignites economic growth in the first place. The answer is likely to vary from case to case: political stabilisation, economic liberalisation, structural reform etc. In the case of Brazil, economic reform and stabilisation under the FHC and Lula governments seem to have triggered such a growth take-off, lifting potential growth to 4% plus, compared to 2.5% previously. However, in order for the virtuous cycle to be sustained, the government needs to allow savings to rise.

Brazilian household and government consumption has been virtually flat (as a share of GDP) during the past few years, although the acceleration in economic growth should have lowered the consumption share in GDP. In countries like China and India, both government and household consumption declined following the growth acceleration over the course of this decade. In Brazil, both households and the government seem to have a much higher propensity to consume. This propensity has been underpinned by strong growth in government consumption and transfers.

Raising private sector savings through public policies is not straightforward, neither politically nor economically, and certainly not in the short term (e.g. pension reform). The government has far greater control over its own consumption and savings behavior. It should therefore rein in the growth of government consumption (and transfers), that is, raise government savings. Whether higher savings are then best utilized to boost public investment, reduce the fiscal deficit (and crowd in private-sector investment) or finance tax cuts, thus raising the appropriable returns on private-sector investment, is a separate debate. If the government fails to rein in expenditure growth, the virtuous cycle of higher growth, investment and savings may be undermined.

Officials frequently point to the significant levels of inequality and poverty and Brazil’s democratic political system in order to rationalize why a reduction in government expenditure is either not desirable or feasible, or both. It is no doubt a fascinating debate to what extent, for example, the ability of the East Asian economies and more recently China to “extract” savings and limit current expenditure growth was conditional on the authoritarian nature of their political systems. The example of India, on the other hand, is more difficult to dismiss. India managed to lift its savings and investment ratio substantially during the course of the last decade, even though India suffers from much higher levels of absolute poverty than Brazil. India is also a democracy that, due to the fragmented nature of its parliamentary system, should find it at least as difficult, if not more difficult, to resist political pressure for higher government spending.

Indian investment and savings ratios increased on the back of both declining household and government consumption. While the contribution to domestic savings from declining household consumption was more marked, government consumption also declined. By contrast, government consumption in Brazil remained conspicuously high (as did current expenditure, including transfers). It may be easier to raise savings on the back of very high economic growth: Indian real GDP growth averaged nearly 8% compared to 5% in Brazil. But Brazilian real GDP growth also almost doubled in recent years, yet government consumption and current spending remained stubbornly high.

The snag is that even if politicians accept the need to raise public-sector savings, it is not in their short-term political interest to rein in electorally rewarding current expenditure growth. With the economy humming along nicely, social security reform is not a viable political option, even if stubbornly high household consumption strongly points to the necessity of encouraging greater household savings. However, a multi-year commitment to slowing current expenditure growth to below the rate of nominal GDP growth should be possible, expenditure rigidity and revenue-earmarking notwithstanding, politically and economically.

Such a reform would probably have to take place at the very beginning of a presidential term (Brazil will hold a presidential election in October 2010) and against the backdrop of significant growth, allowing for a continued solid increase in real expenditure; and it would probably have to go hand in hand with increased public sector investment, allowing the government to reap electoral rewards by way of “pork barrel”-type spending. All said and done: 2011 may be remembered as the year Brazil managed to lift economic growth onto a 5-6% growth path. Or it may simply be remembered as the year when Brazil passed up a tremendous opportunity.