Thursday, December 12, 2013

Structural reform in the BRIC – what needs doing? (2013)

Economic growth in the emerging economies, in general, and in the BRIC, in particular, has slowed down significantly, while for now headline inflation remains quite elevated – China excepted. This points to rising supply constraints and suggests that the growth slowdown is in part structural. Labour markets in Brazil and Russia, for instance, are very tight. While all BRIC economies are in need of productivity-enhancing reform, measures necessary to tackle these constraints vary. 
Hausmann et al. have proposed a framework for the identification of the so-called (most) binding constraint(s) limiting economic growth, called growth diagnostics. Cross-country regression analysis may help identify the factors that constrain economic growth, whether they be low human capital, weak institutions or insufficient capital accumulation. Each country faces a unique set of economic, socio-political etc, conditions, however, and cross-country research singles out the factors that on average support higher economic growth. 
The growth diagnostic strategy, on the other hand, seeks to identify the “the most binding constraints on economic activity, and hence the set of policies that, once targeted on these constraints at any point in time, is likely to provide the biggest bang for the reform buck”. More specifically, Hausmann et al. (2008) propose a decision tree that helps identify the causes of low private investment. The underlying assumption is that it is the level of private investment that in large measure determines future output growth. This framework can be heuristically applied to the BRIC economies. 
Brazil undoubtedly suffers from a high cost of finance. This is, however, not due to bad international finance, for external borrowing costs are very low, but due to a combination of low domestic savings and, arguably, poor financial intermediation. Poor intermediation, in turn, can be attributed to banks’ high reserve requirements and a legal framework that makes it difficult for lenders to recover their losses. Raising domestic (public) savings through a longer-term fiscal adjustment should therefore help address the dearth of domestic savings and lessen the need for high reserve requirements. 
China does not suffer from low private investment and the Hausmannian framework does hence not seem to be applicable here. If anything, it would be desirable to reduce domestic savings through greater fiscal outlays and social expenditure as well as, potentially, by raising the cost capital (aka financial and interest-rate reform) and by forcing SOEs to pay dividends to the government. Financial reform would also help boost household income and potentially reduce the propensity to save. This would help wean the economy off potentially excessive investment and all the risks this entails. China could nonetheless introduce reforms aimed at raising the productivity of investment. This would help it maintain high growth in spite of the anticipated reduction in domestic investment and rise in consumption.

Source: IMF

To the extent that India suffers from low private investment, this can be attributed to low social returns. Interest rates have not historically been very high (in real terms) and governance or market failures would appear to be somewhat less important growth constraints as far as low appropriability is concerned than low social returns and, more specifically, a low level of human capital and a bad infrastructure. Illiteracy is very high and the infrastructure is notoriously poor. Admittedly, market failure is likely the second most important binding constraint in India. India should therefore focus on specific bottlenecks in the energy and infrastructure area as well as reduce market inefficiencies (e.g. accelerated approval of large investment projects, land acquisition law, restrictive labour laws).
Last but not least, the relatively low level of private investment in Russia seems to be primarily due to micro-risks and governance failures and ultimately low appropriability. The cost of finance does not appear to be unduly high and Russia has been running current account surpluses for many years, suggesting excess savings. A poor geography and an at best average-quality infrastructure represent important constraints. But compared to the issues of property risk and corruption, these constraints are arguably less “binding”. Structural reforms aimed at boosting private-sector investment will therefore be key to raise medium-term economic growth. A more efficient state would also help boost the productivity of public investment. But state reform is difficult. WTO accession offers a welcome opportunity to implement structural reforms aimed at making the business environment more predictable, strengthen the rule of law and limit corruption. 

Thursday, September 26, 2013

Financial position of governments in major advanced economies (2013)

Gross general government debt is the most frequently used measure to compare public debt across countries. The general government sector includes the central, state and local governments, including social security funds. On this measure, Japan has the most highly indebted government in the world among the advanced economies with a debt-to-GDP ratio that is rapidly approaching 250% of GDP. A quite different picture emerges if general government and central bank liabilities are consolidated and assets are netted. This translates into government net financial worth. On this measure, Japanese debt is only 100% of GDP. Net financial worth does not take into account the assets and liabilities of state-owned enterprises nor government equity holdings in publicly-traded companies. Here it worth noting that the gross debt of government-related enterprieses amounts to a mere 13% of GDP in Japan, compared to 52% of GDP in the US. Net financial worth also fails account for non-financial assets owned by the government such as as land, buildings and structures. As of 2010, these were equivalent to 120% of GDP in Japan, compared to 66% of GDP in the US. Last but not least, Japan’s implicit liabilities (aka NPV value of projected increases in pension- healthcare spending during 2011-50 is a mere 34% of GDP, compared to 210% of GDP in the US. The Japanese government’s position does not compare too badly, after all. Naturally, the deterioration of the government’s financial position at the margin (aka fiscal deficits) is of concern and needs to be tackled sooner or later.

Government assets & liabilities (% of GDP)
Source: IMF


Wednesday, September 25, 2013

Demographic change and government debt sustainability in Brazil (2013)

Brazilian government debt has been declining over the past decade, falling from more than 60% of GDP in 2002 to 35% of GDP today. The current fiscal stance is compatible with a decline of the debt ratio of 1-2 percentage points a year. Gross general government debt, the more widely used indicator for purposes of cross-country comparisons, remains relatively high. But this is to a large extent due to the accumulation of FX reserves by the central bank and sizeable government lending to the state development bank. 

Moreover, even a tangible increase in gross general government debt would be unlikely to cause problems. Assuming, very conservatively, a real interest rate of 7%, real GDP growth of 3%, and taking into account the lower financial return on government assets (mainly FX reserves, loans to BNDES) relative to their financing costs, general government debt could increase by 20-30% of GDP from current levels without jeopardising public-sector solvency. With government debt on a downward trajectory, however, the equilibrium real interest rate is not likely to rise back to its historical average – and each 100bp decline allows the government to reduce its primary surplus by an additional 0.4-0.5% of GDP. 

Over the medium to long term, rising social security and health outlays on the back of aging demographics will put pressure on the evolution of public finances. The combination of a generous social security regime – Brazil spends way more as a share of GDP than other economies with a comparable level of per capita income and is experiencing, at the margin, a more rapid change of its demographic profile – may turn into an increasingly important fiscal challenge over the medium to long term. The net present value of the increase in pension and health-related expenditure exceeds 100% of GDP in Brazil. A rapidly rising (albeit from a low level) old-age dependency ratio combined with generous social security benefits will sooner or later force the government’s hand. 


Source: IMF

Thursday, September 19, 2013

Sovereign balance sheets in Brazil and Turkey (2013)

In the early 2000s, both Brazil and Turkey experienced severe financial crises. Currency depreciation and public sector solvency concerns in the context of significant liability dollarisation pushed both countries to the verge of default. Luckily, both countries embarked upon successful IMF-supervised economic adjustment programme under new governments and experienced a decade of solid economic growth. Coincidentally (maybe) both countries have recently been experiencing wide-spread popular protests, albeit for a variety of different reasons. Arguably, the economic stabilisation of the past decade and the emergence of a politically vocal middle class have played a role here. But this is a separate topic. Let’s focus on economics.
The combination of fiscal adjustment and growth acceleration underpinned improving government solvency. In Brazil, net public sector debt has fallen from more than 60% of GDP in 2002 to 35% of GDP today. Gross general government debt - the more widely used indicator for purposes of cross-country comparisons - remains relatively elevated at 69% of GDP. The more limited decline of gross debt is to some extent due to central bank’s sterilised FX intervention and accumulation policy as well as sizeable off-balance financial transactions in the guise of lending to public sector banks. In Turkey, net general government debt has fallen a little faster than in Brazil, decreasing from 70% of GDP in 2002 to less than 30% of GDP today. Gross general government debt has fallen by much more than in Brazil and today stands at around 36% of GDP.
Both sovereigns have successfully reduced their (net) foreign-currency (FCY) exposure. At end-2012, Brazil’s sovereign net FCY creditor position was 14.2% of GDP, compared to Turkey’s 1.7% of GDP. Both countries have largely eliminated domestically-issued FCY(-linked), while a decade ago, 30-40% of domestically-issued government debt in both countries was linked to the exchange rate. In Brazil, the general government domestic debt is 55.8% of GDP, compared to total debt of 58.7% in 2012. By comparison, Turkey’s domestic debt amounts to 28.4% of GDP, compared to a total of 37.6% of GDP. The Brazilian central bank holds FCY assets worth 14% of GDP, roughly the same as in Turkey, translating into net FCY creditor  position in both cases.
A sovereign net FCY creditor position means that, unlike a decade ago, exchange depreciation leads to a decline – rather than a significant rise – in the net debt-to-GDP ratio. Accumulating large FX reserves does come at a direct financial cost, however. First of all, the central bank typically sells government bonds from its portfolio to absorb the additional liquidity created by FX purchases, thus effectively financing lower-yielding FCY-denominated assets by way of higher-yielding local-currency (LCY) government debt. Moreover, to the extent that a currency is undervalued in real terms, reducing net FCY debt deprives the sovereign of the opportunity to reduce the LCY value of FCY liabilities by way of real currency appreciation. Last but not least, the resulting larger stock of domestic LCY debt will tend to help keep domestic interest rates high. 
On the flipside, a large net FCY creditor position (aka large FX reserves) provides the authorities with more ammunition to intervene in the FX market and provide FCY funding to domestic financial institutions and corporates in case of a “sudden shock” (e.g. Brazil in 2008-09). Brazil certainly has a much a more favourable external liquidity position than Turkey. It may be worth noting that the CBRT’s net international FX reserves amount to less than half its reported reserves after adjusting for domestic banks’ FX deposits with the central bank. In practice, this may not make a significant difference, but in this respect Brazil’s position is more favourable, too.
While both the Turkish government and the banking sector can sustain even a large exchange rate shock, limited FCY liquidity means that the impact in terms of higher interest rates, lower local liquidity and economic growth will be much more significant than in Brazil. It is no coincidence that Turkish real GDP declined dramatically in late 2008 and early 2009, while the Brazilian economy only registered a very mild decline in output. Turkey is no doubt more exposed to a sudden stop, and while the government and the banking sector seem well-positioned to withstand significant exchange rate depreciation, the authorities have significantly less scope to soften the impact of such a shock as far as external liquidity is concerned. 
Interestingly, Brazil’s significantly more favourable FCY position does not translate into lower sovereign risk as reflected in CDS spreads. Curiously, as of early July Brazilian 5Y CDS spreads traded at 195 bp versus 180 bps in Turkey. Naturally, Turkey’s gross and, less so, net public sector debt is lower than Brazil’s. But its external position, if not vulnerable, is undoubtedly more sensitive to an external shock than Brazil’s. It looks as if the benefits Brazil derives from a large sovereign FCY creditor position in terms of markets’ perception of sovereign risk are at best very limited compared to Turkey, while it undoubtedly translates into higher (quasi-) fiscal costs. Nominal and real interest rates in Brazil remain significantly higher than in Turkey. That said, large FCY holdings do make Brazil less susceptible to a sudden stop than Turkey. Think of greater quasi-fiscal costs as an insurance premium.

Wednesday, September 4, 2013

Government debt sustainability in the emerging markets (2013)

Governments in the advanced economies are facing sizeable short-, medium- and long-term debt sustainability challenges. By contrast, government debt in the EM has been trending down due to a combination of solid economic growth, low interest rates and, with only a few exceptions, sustainable fiscal policies. More specifically: gross general government debt is set to remain stable or decline over the next five years, with the possible exception of Russia. But Russia has by far the lowest level of government debt among the top-tier EM and the rise in debt is likely to be negligible. Moreover, if the government’s non-equity financial assets are taken into account, the government is a net creditor. 
If implicit debt is taken into account, a somewhat less straightforward picture begins to emerge. If the implicit debt stemming from the increase in pension- and health-expenditure is taken into account (and adequately discounted), countries like China and Russia, the two countries with the lowest government debt level, begin to compare much less favourably to countries with large public debt burden, like India, but with limited implicit pension- and healthcare liabilities. According to the IMF, the NPV value of spending increases in 2010-50 is in the 200-300% of GDP range for China, Russia, Korea and Turkey, and less than 100% of GDP for India, Mexico, Indonesia and Poland. Naturally, this is not meant to suggest that these liabilities were materialise. Pension and healthcare reforms do take place and fiscal policy can be adjusted to deal with the impending rise in spending and liabilities.
Historically, emerging markets (EM) have tended to get into financial trouble on account of their FCY debt. In addition to a decline in government debt, the share of FCY debt as a share of total debt has fallen in virtually all EM. At the same time, increased FX reserves have substantially reduced – and in many cases – eliminated potentially risky net sovereign FCY exposure of the public sector. The public sectors of most top-tier EM are net FCY creditors. In effect, this means that currency depreciation results in a reduction of net public debt. Many EM have replaced FCY debt owed to foreigners with LCY debt owed to foreigners (thus overcoming the so-called “original sin”).

Source: IMF

Last but not least, while fiscal deficits are quite small, generally less than 3% of GDP (with the significant exception of India), and consistent with stable-to-declining debt-to-GDP ratios over the medium term, gross financing requirements remain large, at least by EM standards. In 2013, they will range from 17% of GDP in Brazil to basically zero in Korea. Both gross and net financing requirements have generally been declining, or at least they have not been increasing, in recent years. In many cases, the maturity structure of domestic debt has improved. Government refinancing risks are very manageable, not least because medium-term debt sustainability and credit risk is generally not an issue. After all, non-resident holdings of government debt in countries with large financing needs are low as a share of GDP – and vice versa. Like in most other EM, sovereign risk is mitigated by manageable underlying debt dynamics, limited-to-non-existent FCY mismatches and the fact that where foreigners make up a significant share of the investor base they tend to hold longer-duration debt. 




Thursday, August 22, 2013

Demographics and economics in Germany, Japan and the US (2013)

Demographic dynamics affect economic growth via savings and labour supply dynamics. A falling dependency ratio tends to translate into lower savings, while a rising old-age dependency ratio typically raises government expenditure on account of rising pension and health expenditure. 

In Germany and Japan, the potential labour supply (population of working age) has already begun to decline. Not surprisingly, this has translated into a much diminished contribution of labour to economic growth. Investment has fallen in Germany, Japan and the US, resulting in a smaller contribution of capital formation to output growth than in the past. This has affected per capita real GDP growth in all three countries.

While Germany’s gross savings ratio has fluctuated between 20-25% of GDP since 1980, gross savings in Japan and the US have declined. Japan’s savings and investment behavior matches the demographic-economic model’s prediction most closely. By contrast, German (household) savings have held up well (and even increased). Germany and Japan run sizeable current account surpluses (= savings – investment), while the US has been running a deficit for several decades.

According to the OECD, old-age-related social expenditure rose from 8.2% of GDP in 1990 to 13% in 2009 in Japan. During the same period, it fell from 9.4% to 9.1% in Germany, while it rose from 5.2% to 6.1% in the US. Similar trends can be observed in terms of total social security expenditure .

Under current legislation, government spending on pension and health care is set to increase in all three countries. In spite of worse demographics, Germany and Japan seem much better positioned than the US in this respect. US government spending on pensions and health is set increase to almost 6% of GDP over the coming decades, while both Germany and Japan will experience far less dramatic increases. A lot will, of course, depend on how entitlement spending will be reformed in the coming decades. As of now, however, the US appears far less favourably positioned than Germany and Japan – despite a far more favourable demographic profile.

Source: IMF

Friday, August 9, 2013

Who’s afraid of declining commodity prices? (2013)

Commodity prices have increased sharply over the past ten years. Large populous emerging economies, first and foremost China, have become major consumers of commodities as they build out their infrastructure, their per capita income and nutrition patterns change and their populations become more mobile and thus consume more energy. Time will tell whether we currently find ourselves in the midst of a commodity super-cycle, or not. Either way, it is worth and prudent to ask which emerging markets would be the most sensitive to a sustained drop in commodity prices.

As far as the balance of payments is concerned, it is evident that Russia (negatively) and Korea (positively) are the two EM that would be most affected by a decline in commodity prices. Whether one looks at it in terms of the share of commodities in total exports or in terms of net exports, the same picture emerges. Russia is the one country among the EM-10 most sensitive to a decline in commodity prices, followed by Indonesia, Brazil, South Africa and Mexico. Russia’s net commodity exports amounted to almost 20% of GDP in 2011. While Indonesia and Brazil also rely on commodity exports, their lower degree of overall openness and lower net commodity exports renders them less sensitive to swings in commodity prices. Concentration measures of exports by product and country paint a roughly similar picture. Russia is the EM-10 most heavily concentrated in terms of its export profile, followed by South Africa, Indonesia and Brazil.

Furthermore, the price of energy has increased the most among the major commodity classes. This may or may not point to greater price risk going forward. It is certainly true, however, that both Brazil and Indonesia, while reliant on commodity exports, have a significantly more diversified commodity export base than Russia. In Brazil, for instance, this base consists of iron ore, soy, sugar, poultry and crude oil. Again, Russia is by far the EM most susceptible to a decline in commodity prices.

The net commodity importers, on the other hand, would benefit from a decline in commodity prices: Korea and Turkey would stand to benefit the most from lower commodity prices. In fact, Turkey’s entire external deficit is pretty much accounted f or by net commodity imports (especially energy). Improving terms of trade (aka lower commodity import prices) would tangibly improve the outlook for the current account. China, India and, less so, Poland would also stand to benefit from softer commodity prices.

At present oil prices, Russia will run a current account surplus in 2013-14. Russia’s non-energy current account deficit is around 15% of GDP. Assuming inelastic import demand, a 20% drop in oil prices sustained would quickly push the current account into deficit towards 3% of GDP. Susceptibility is not the same as vulnerability, of course. After all, the capacity to raise financing or the ready availability of liquid foreign assets can greatly mitigate even a severe current account shock. Moreover, how vulnerable a country is will also depend on the pre-shock financing metrics.

In terms of gross financing requirements relative to FX reserves, Russia benefits from a very solid position. Thanks to more than USD 500bn of FX reserves, Russia could easily finance a current account deficit of 3% of GDP. Even if short-term debt as well as debt amortisations are taken into account, external financing requirements (EFR) are very small compared to FX reserves. The international liquidity ratio (ILR), which captures short-term external debt plus non-resident holdings of domestic government plus debt amortisations relative to liquid foreign assets (central bank and commercial banks’ assets), paints a very similar picture. Only China with its USD 3.4 tr worth of FX reserves and minimal non-resident holdings of domestic debt has more favourable EFR and ILR ratios.

As far as the governments’ reliance on commodity-related revenues is concerned, Russia would also be the EM most directly affected by a general decline in commodity prices. Russia’s non-oil fiscal deficit is equivalent to 10% of GDP. However, the reliance on oil revenues is significantly mitigated by the existence of more than 8% of GDP worth of fiscal reserves the government could draw on to finance shortfalls if energy prices collapsed. (Naturally, if oil prices were to remain depressed for long, the government would soon be forced into a longer-term fiscal adjustment.) Last but not least, gross government debt is very low at 12% of GDP and the IMF estimates the net financial worth of the Russian government to be more than 20% of GDP (financial debt minus financial assets). In short, it would require a multi-year downward movement in the energy price cycle for the Russian government’s net worth to erode.

In Brazil and South Africa as well as in Indonesia, by comparison, natural resources companies are largely owned by the private sector, even if the government in some cases receives dividends as a major shareholder (e.g. Brazil) and benefits indirectly from higher commodity prices via corporate taxes. In Indonesia, oil- and gas-related revenues make up 3% of GDP, significantly less than in Russia. In Brazil and South Africa, the direct and indirect reliance on commodity-related revenues is even smaller. The degree of dependence of these three countries is therefore in no way comparable to Russia. Interestingly, the Mexican government, only barely a net commodity exporter, would be significantly more vulnerable to a prolonged downturn in oil prices given that around 1/3 of government revenues stem from the state-owned oil company and that, unlike in Russia, the government’s fiscal reserves (aka oil savings fund) are very small.

Tuesday, July 9, 2013

Time for China to become more Brazilian (2013)

What could China possibly learn from Brazil, economically? After all, real GDP growth in Brazil averaged 2.75% annually over the past three decades, compared to 10% in China. Moreover, Brazil’s consumption-oriented growth model is about to exhaust itself, while China’s investment-focussed strategy continues to generate high, if somewhat diminished economic growth. Factor in the social, environmental and political consequences and it becomes clear that China’s growth model needs to change as well. Therefore: Brazil would be well-advised to become more “Chinese” in terms of savings and investment behaviour, while China would benefit from becoming more “Brazilian” in terms of consuming more (saving less).

Brazil’s economic growth has disappointed in the past couple of years. After increasing more than 7% in 2010, real GDP growth decelerated to 2.7% and 0.9% in 2011 and 2012, respectively. Even if real GDP growth recovers to slightly more than 3% this year, it will be below the 4% growth level Brazil got accustomed to over the past decade. While economic growth has disappointed, household consumption has remained resilient due to rising incomes, tight labour markets and the greater availability of household credit. Investment growth, by contrast, has been very weak, especially in the manufacturing sector. This is largely due to rising labour costs, a strong currency and a lack of productivity-enhancing structural reform. Brazil may be showing symptoms of Dutch disease.

The combination of strong consumption and relatively weak investment growth will sooner rather than later force the authorities to choose between higher inflation and lower growth – if this has not already happened. For now, the president continues to benefit from high approval ratings, recent protests notwithstanding, against the backdrop of a strong labour market, rising household incomes and expanding consumption. But the government seems to have realised that greater investment is necessary to keep employment and income growth going over the medium term. The government has been seeking to expand lending by public-sector banks, accelerate public-sector investment, reduce labour and production costs through tax cuts and exemptions and create and/or offer more favourable conditions for/to private investment in infrastructure projects (e.g. sales of infrastructure concessions). Unfortunately, this has thus far failed to trigger a rise in domestic investment.

Chinese GDP growth has slowed down from more than 10% a year to a still high 8% or so. Nonetheless, capital-intensive growth is having an increasingly adverse ecological impact. Investment-led combined with export-oriented growth makes the economy more vulnerable to exogenous shocks and creates incentives to engage in potentially risky quasi-fiscal stimulus policies (2008-09). Last but not least, more service-sector and consumption-oriented growth would be more employment intensive. As such, the political incentives to modify the growth strategy certainly exist, and they are growing larger.

Admittedly, Chinese household consumption is growing rapidly, but so is GDP, while household income remains very small as a share of GDP. Savings remain high across the government, corporate and household sector. Household savings are high in part due to an under-developed social security regime, creating significant incentives to accumulate precautionary savings. Household incomes are weighed down by extra-low returns on household assets due to financial repression. By contrast, corporate savings and investment are high due to a favourable tax and dividend regime as well as an undervalued exchange rate and cheap credit, favouring investment in the export-oriented, capital-intensive manufacturing sector. China has taken measures to raise domestic consumption, mainly by expanding social welfare coverage, providing tax incentives and gradually appreciating the exchange rate. Plans to liberalise interest rates, thus boosting household incomes and raising the cost of capital, and to raise corporate dividend pay-outs are also in the works, amongst others.


Source: IMF

The structural differences between Brazil and China have thus remained very striking. In Brazil, the household sector has limited incentives to generate precautionary savings. An extensive social security and pension regime incentivises households to consume rather than save. In China, the household sector faces the opposite problem: the social welfare regime is not very extensive. In Brazil, the corporate sector is facing very high borrowing costs (in part due to low domestic savings), which limits profitability. In China, the corporate sector has access to very cheap funding due to high savings and financial repression. In Brazil, the exchange rate is overvalued, limiting the incentives to invest in export-oriented industries, while in China the exchange rate - at least until recently - had been undervalued, favouring investment in the export-oriented manufacturing sector. The list goes on.

Policy-makers in both countries have acknowledged the need to adjust their economic strategies; and the political incentives to adapt their respective models do exist, too. Both governments have taken a number of measures in the past few years, but respective consumption/ savings patterns have changed only little in the past few years. Chinese savings have declined a little, but investment is actually higher today than it was before 2008-09. (While the combination of higher investment and somewhat lower savings/ higher consumption has helped narrow the politically-contentious external surplus, it has made the economy even more dependent on investment.) Admittedly, neither Brazil nor China has taken overly aggressive measures to achieve their respective objectives. But savings, consumption and investment patterns perhaps only change slowly.

Perhaps fundamental factors such as demographic trends and cultural or historically-inherited attitudes (e.g. hyper-inflation) are also at work. This does not mean that government policies will not have any effects – only that they need to be pursued more forcefully if Brazil and China are to shift their economic growth models towards greater investment and greater consumption, respectively.

Monday, June 24, 2013

Of reversing the Great Divergence and passing the baton (2013)

Economies’ relative weight has been changing rather dramatically over the past few decades – most notably in the case of China. At the beginning of economic reforms in the late seventies, following almost half a century of economic and political instability, China’s share of global GDP was a mere 2.2%, according to the IMF. By 2020, its share is set to exceed 20%. Economic historians estimate that China acounted for 1/3 of global economic output in 1820, just before what has come to be known as the “great divergence” (Pomeranz 2000). In 2017, China will replace the US as the world’s largest economy (in PPP terms). This will be the first time since 1872 – when the US overtook Britain as the world’s largest economy – that a new “number one” will emerge. Between 1870 and 1910, the US nearly doubled its share of world output from less than 9% to almost 16%. Following the devastation of most major economies, the US emerged from WWII accounting for 27% of world GDP. With the recovery of war-devastated economies, the US share began to decline. On current trends, the US share will continue to decline and the Chinese share will continue to increase, but India will be just about the only country with the potential to replace the US as the world’s second-largest economy. But this is unlikely to happen before 2050. Beyond India, there are simply no other potential contenders.


Source: IMF

Monday, June 10, 2013

Which of the emerging economies is afraid of higher interest rates? (2013)

The emerging markets weathered the 2008-09 global financial crisis without sustaining structural damage. True, a small number of EMs received liquidity support from the IMF. But thanks to by and large sound fundamentals, the EMs adjusted to the capital (and current) account shock through a combination of FX depreciation, central bank liquidity support and domestic economic contraction. In the past few years, global financial conditions have been very supportive, as reflected in ultra-loose monetary policies in the major advanced economies and strong capital flows to the (higher-yielding) EMs. So it may be time to ask which EMs are most exposed to a sharp slowdown in capital flows.

A variety of indicators are used to gauge an economy’s sensitivity to capital account shocks. Perhaps the most commonly used one is external financing requirements (EFR). EFR are equivalent to short-term debt, medium- and long-term debt amortisations and the current account in relation to FX reserves. Admittedly, in today’s world where the capital accounts of the major EMs are relatively open and foreign investors hold in some cases significant amounts of LCY-denominated portfolio debt and equity, potential balance-of-payments pressure can far exceed EFR.

However, it is clear that non-resident LCY - and especially equity-claims will weigh far less on the balance-of-payments than short-term FCY-denominated debt claims. This is particularly true in the case of economies with floating exchange rates. Moreover, EFR do not include either non-reserve assets or foreign assets held by the private sector. In spite of these limitations, EFR provide a fair idea as to the potential vulnerability of an EM in the event of an external liquidity shock.

A rule of thumb says that an EFR ratio of less than 100% is “safe” in terms of even a severe balance-of-payments crisis. In fact the Greenspan-Guidotti rule says that FX reserves should at least be equivalent to short-term foreign debt (on a residual maturity basis). Given that EFR include current account related financing needs, EFR of less than 100% are therefore reflective of a pretty solid liquidity risk profile. Moreover, China, Korea and Russia run small current account surpluses, but short-term debt (on a residual basis) in all these countries amounts to less than 50% of FX reserves in 2013. The EFRs are especially favourable given that most of the large EMs have relatively free-floating exchange rates. China and Russia, the EMs with the least flexible currency regime, incidentally have the lowest EFR. Only Turkey is bit of an outlier. Last but not least, it is worth comparing current EFR to those observed just before the massive global shock of 2008. Korea, Poland (not even taking account IMF FCL) and South Africa have much stronger positions, while India and Indonesia have slightly weaker (but still solid) positions (< 100%). Only Turkey’s EFR are today both higher than in 2008 and above the 100% threshold.

In the past, so-called sudden stops or capital flow reversals often translated into higher government debt ratios and worsening sovereign risk. If FCY risk is concentrated in the systemically important sector government or banking sector, a capital flows shock can quickly transmute into a systemic crisis. Today, however, the consolidated public sectors in all major EMs are net FCY creditors. Many EMs have put in place regulations limiting the extent to which banks can run FCY risk, while more flexible exchange rate have removed banks’ incentives to run open FCY positions, thus limiting FCY risk in the systemically important banking sector.

To sum up, the top-10 emerging economies appear well-prepared to withstand a significant tightening of external financing conditions. External liquidity indicators are roughly comparable to those observed just before the massive 2008 global financial shock. Turkey is the EM most sensitive to tightening financial conditions on account of both its large short-term external debt and large current account deficit. Thanks to limited FCY mismatches in the government and banking sectors, an adverse external liquidity shock would translate into currency depreciation and a potentially sharp economic slowdown à la 2008-09. To what extent such a scenario would impact the corporate sector, where virtually all of the FCY risk is concentrated, and to what extent this would impact the banking sector’s financial position by way of their FCY lending to the domestic corporate sector would in part depend on how prolonged currency weakness and the economic slowdown last. Systemic risks appear nonetheless manageable for now, not least because the banking sector is well-capitalised.

Thursday, May 30, 2013

Gross government debt vs government net worth (2013)

Gross general government is the most frequently used indicator in terms of cross-country comparisons. The concepts covers the financial liabilities of the central and sub-national governments. While it takes into account social security funds, it does not include the liabilities of financial or non-financial government-owned enterprises. It also fails to account for government assets. Net general government debt, for instance, nets out the general government’s financial liabilities and assets (with the exception of shares, equity and derivatives). Consolidating the assets and liabilities of both the general government sector and the central bank, one arrives at ”net financial worth of the consolidated government and central bank sector”. One could go further and take into account non-financial assets owned by the government (e.g. buildings, land) to arrive at “net worth.” Last but not least, one could add the assets and liabilities of government-owned companies as well as government equity holdings of partly privatised enterprises into the mix to arrive the broader public sector’s net worth. If nothing else, the broader concepts suggest that in terms of stock (if not necessarily, flows), the financial position of many advanced economy governments are not as bad as the general government debt concept might suggest – especially in the case of Japan.

Wednesday, May 22, 2013

Monetary power & European monetary integration (2012)

Germany’s economic power allowed it to extend its economic model on the rest of Europe. It is not just Germany, of course. Other countries share German policy preferences, largely creditor nations. Germany’s economic power has been increasing over the past few decades. Today Germany is economically and financially the dominant economy in Europe. As such, its ability to influence the economic policies of other countries and its ability to influence the future evolution of the European macroeconomic policy regime is considerable. 
What are the sources of German economic power? First, Germany is the largest economy. Second, Germany has very strong public finances. Third, the capacity to raise debt is significant. Fourth, Germany runs external surpluses and is a large net foreign creditor. Without German’s financial strength, any bail-out regime will be inadequate. This effectively means that German non-participation dooms any bail-out regime. If, for example, Finland decided not to contribute to a financial rescue, it would not significant diminish the regime. That said, rising trade and financial integration has also made Germany both more sensitive and vulnerable. Economic-financial interdependence often is asymmetric and this asymmetry provides Germany with a great deal of influence in European economic and financial affairs. 
The (West) German economy has been characterized by a specific combination of institutions, ideology and interests, creating a German model of macroeconomic management. The combination of these institutions somewhat inadvertently led to the rise of Germany structural power (Strange). In a way, Germany obtained economic power as inadvertently as some people say Britain acquired its empire: in a fit of absent-mindedness.
What institutions underpin the German model? First, the West German government established an independent central bank tasked with maintaining low inflation. (This was largely the result of the experience with hyperinflation in the 1920s.) By contrast, central banks in other major West European countries were not as independent or not independent at all. Germany was able to establish a track record of monetary stability and maintain inflation rates at levels consistently below those of the other major European economies, such as France, Italy and the UK. 
Second, the government made far more modest use of an activist fiscal policy to support economic growth. Keynesianism experienced only a very short-lived popularity in the late 60s and early 70s. Ultimately, it was the priority accorded to price stability rather than growth and an independent central bank unwilling to accommodate expansionary fiscal policies that put paid to activist fiscal policies. A relatively high degree of economic openness also limited the effectiveness of fiscal stimulus measures. Last but not least, German ordo-liberal thinking dominated economic policy. More speculatively, Germany, aware of its precarious position as a frontline state, was also more concerned about high public debt than other European countries.
Third, the structure of the German wage bargaining system, dominated by unions in the export sector, typically resulted in wage moderation. Thus export openness contributed to relatively lower wage inflation (adjusted for productivity) than in other countries where wage bargaining was dominated by unions operating in sheltered sectors, including public services, or more militant unions, period. An independent central bank whose actions would have helped increase unemployment rather than accommodate inflationary wage settlements was important. The wage bargaining ha undergone important changes since the nineties, but it remains geared to preserving German economic competitiveness.
These institutional features created a macroeconomic policy regime that prioritized low inflation over economic growth and ended up relying on exports for economic growth rather than activist and potentially debt-increasing fiscal policies. Not only did this allow Germany to establish a track record of monetary and fiscal probity. It also contributed to structural trade and current account surpluses throughout much of the post-war period. The commitment to financial stability and external surpluses increased German power as Europe became economically and financially more integrated. This became increasingly evident following the break-up of the Bretton Woods system and the creation of (various) European exchange rate regimes.
In the context of balance-of-payments imbalances, power derives from the “capacity to avoid the burden of adjustment required by payments imbalance” (Cohen 2006: chapter 2). This provides the surplus country with autonomy and constrains the policy space of the deficit country. While the surplus country is autonomous, the deficit country will sooner or later be forced to either devalue (so-called expenditure-switching policies) or adjust monetary and fiscal policies (expenditure-changing policies) to address the external disequilibrium. The external equilibrium needs to be restored via decreased domestic absorption and increased exports. 
The autonomy of the surplus country is reflected in its greater power to delay and deflect economic adjustment. If the deficit country does not adjust, it will eventually run out of reserves, as the markets will become unwilling to finance the deficit. The surplus country, by contrast, is able to hold out much longer by absorbing balance-of-payments surpluses in to FX reserves. This may or may not have economic consequences somewhere down the line (e.g. inflation). But it is clear that, unlike the deficit country, the surplus country can choose to resist nominal exchange rate appreciation more easily and is less readily forced to adjust its macroeconomic policy mix. In general, the surplus country finding it easier to both delay and deflect adjustment is able to stick to its macroeconomic preferences, while the deficit country is not. 
It is useful to distinguish between the permanent costs of adjustment and the transitional costs. The transitional costs associated with a change in economic policy typically falls on the deficit country. The permanent economic costs in terms of output and domestic consumption are always shared, even though they are typically felt much more strongly in the deficit country. After all, the deficit country needs to reduce domestic absorption and export more, while the surplus country (in a two-country model, at least) will need to increase domestic absorption and reduce exports, if balance is to be restored. Put differently, a devaluation of the deficit currency will lead to the revaluation of the surplus currency. The question hence is which country will adjust its economic policies and sacrifice or compromise its macroeconomic policy preferences. For instance, will the deficit country forego growth in the interest of monetary and fiscal discipline, or will the surplus compromise its monetary and fiscal discipline in order to help restore the external equilibrium.
This analysis becomes especially relevant in the context of fixed (but adjustable) exchange rate and particularly in the presence of an open capital account. There the so-called ‘unholy trinity’ emerges. In this context, the ability of the deficit countries to pursue an independent monetary and, to some extent, fiscal policy is heavily constrained. The country that benefits from the largest current account surpluses, the largest government debt market and the greatest financial credibility will tend to be the only country capable of pursuing an independent monetary and fiscal policy. Even the lesser surplus countries often find their policies constrained the so-called anchor country. If the capital account is closed, countries enjoy (short-term) policy flexibility, even if expansionary policies will ultimately result in devaluation. If the capital account is completely open, even short-term policy flexibility does not exist if the exchange rate peg is to be maintained. 
Source: Economist

Again, this does not mean that the stronger country is an invulnerable position in terms of the permanent adjustment costs. It simply puts it into a relatively less vulnerable position. For instance, a massive currency devaluation of a deficit country will lead to greater economic turmoil there in the surplus country that will see its currency appreciate, not least because the economy of the devaluing currency is only one among many trading partners of the surplus economy.
The emergence of a fixed exchange rate regime in the 1970s and an increasingly open capital account regime in the 1980s in Europe led to the emergence of the deutschmark as the anchor currency in Europe. It increased the constraints on economic policies other countries were able to pursue. This provided Germany with structural power vis-à-vis other European countries. Structural power is the power of a state to indirectly influence others by controlling the structures within which they must operate (Strange 1996). 
This type of power is not relational, however, in the sense that while it constrains it does not lend itself as a tool to exercise direct influence on another actor’s behaviour. Structural power  (Susan Strange) confers broad policy autonomy, but it does provide the anchor county with direct leverage of other countries’ economic policies. Ultimately, countries not willing to be constrained in this way could always opt to float their currencies, typically at manageable economic - but not necessarily political - costs. Last but not least, structural power does not translate into readily quantifiable, tangibly economic gains, either. It simply means that the structurally dominant country can pursue its preferred economic policy, while indirectly and inadvertently forcing others to adjust their policies.
Famously, this type of power was put into relief during the early 1990s. Reunification had led to a rising demand and price pressures in the German economy, leading the Bundesbank to raise interest rates. However, other ERM countries were cyclically in a very different position. In the face of ‘speculative’ attacks, a number of countries were forced to devalue. This demonstrates neatly the structural nature of German power. German policy-makers, unlike others, enjoyed policy autonomy. By taking advantage of this autonomy, they set the constraints under which other policy-makers had to operate. By contrast, the other countries saw their own policy space heavily constrained.
The advent of EMU and actually one of the reasons why EMU came into existence was because the deficit countries were eager to remove the balance-of-payments constrained and thus diminish German power by supra-nationalising monetary policy. In the context of a monetary union (read: irrevocably fixed exchange rates), balance-of-payments deficits will always be financed by the private- or, failing this, by the official sector. On the flipside, the fiscal constraint becomes tighter for financially/ fiscally weaker countries. Fiscal problems cannot easily be addressed by way of a growth-boosting devaluation. The lack of control over monetary policy removes a further tool to address fiscal imbalances, at least in the short term. Put differently, monetary union removes expenditure-switching (read: devaluation) as a policy option and leaves weaker countries only with expenditure-changing policies (read: fiscal austerity).

The move from fixed (but adjustable) exchange rates to monetary union helped enhance the power of the economically stronger country in similar way the move from a closed to a an open capital account in the context of a fixed exchange rate regime strengthened the power of the surplus country. Similar to balance-of-payments imbalances, large fiscal deficits and/ or rapidly rising debt weaken the policy autonomy of the financially weak country. The fiscally stronger country, enjoying superior access to market funding at cheaper rates, enjoys far greater policy autonomy. Similarly, the ability of the fiscally weaker country to defer or deflect adjustment compared with the country with sound public finances is much weaker. The strong country can choose to maintain fiscal discipline or it can decide to pursue expansionary policies, thus supporting the short-term adjustment of the fiscally weaker countries via higher growth. However, not facing immediate market pressure to adjust policies, it is in a position to delay and deflect adjustment. The financial weak country is not. 
Again, adjustment is always mutual, complementary and shared in the sense of the eventual economic costs. They are also typically much larger in the case of the weaker country. The question is once more who will bear the transitional costs in terms of adjusting fiscal policies. Will the fiscally stronger country boost domestic demand and, especially in the context of fixed rather than flexible exchange rate, help boost economic growth in fiscal weaker country, thus supporting adjustment there. Or the will the fiscally weaker country be forced into fiscal retrenchment, potentially leading to a decline in economic growth and a further deterioration of the fiscal position. To a significant degree, this is a question of whose policy preferences will prevail and which country will absorb the ‘transitional costs of the adjustment’. 
The fiscally and financially stronger country is not invulnerable. Fiscal austerity will reduce export growth and, more extreme, a sovereign default would typically lead to financial losses in the fiscally stronger country to the extent that it holds claims. Potential financial contagion could further raise the economic and financial costs. However, the costs to the defaulting country will almost always by far exceed the costs incurred by the financially stronger country. The stronger country may not be invulnerable, but its relative stronger position confers its significant leverage vis-à-vis financially weaker governments by way of the provision of conditional financing. This leverage does lend itself more easily to the exercise of relational power, that is, the power get another state to take actions it would otherwise not have taken.
The sources of German financial and ultimately relational power are similar to the sources of structural power in the case of balance-of-payments imbalances. In addition to running external surpluses and having established a solid monetary and financial track record, other factors matter.
First, Germany is among the larger European economies the one with greatest borrowing and lending capacity. This is currently reflected in lower debt ratios, a lower fiscal deficit, an AAA credit rating and, most revealingly, in low yields on government debt. The combination of economic size and borrowing capacity makes Germany the most powerful country in terms of its ability to extend credit to other countries in financial need.
Second, Germany is constitutionally obliged to run a structural surplus (so-called ‘debt brake’). This provides investors with some assurance that government finances will remain on a sustainable path. Moreover, from a more short-term perspective, Germany’s short- and medium-term fiscal outlook will not force it to implement growth-diminishing fiscal austerity. It also has a greater capacity to generate economic growth through extra-EMU exports, offsetting weaker intra-EMU exports, than most other European economies. 
Third, German debt is a ‘safe haven’ asset for EUR investors in the context of monetary union. Due to its track record of monetary and financial stability as well as its large current account surpluses, investors are willing to lend to Germany in times of market stress, typically at very favourable conditions. This has thus far led to an easing of Germany financing conditions, further underlining its continued ‘anchor’ economy function in the context of EMU.
In short, the Germany benefits from the largest borrowing capacity and the most favourable interest rates. The resulting ability to offer financial support to other governments, bilaterally or multilaterally, provides it with political leverage. Due to its ability to offer conditional financial support in exchange for a change in policy, Germany is the most powerful country in Europe as far as economic policy is concerned. EMU has enhanced not only enhanced German power by narrowing the policy and especially fiscal policy space of the other European countries relative to Germany. Naturally, this is not necessarily a permanent feature of EMU. Germany’s strength is to some extent the function of lack of fiscal discipline and/ or prudence in other countries. EMU has also led to a qualitative change. Power is (much more) relational today, as opposed to (primarily) structural pre-EMU. Germany certainly is not in a position to single-handedly bail out the rest of the Eurozone governments, but its participation in any rescue effort is indispensable if it is to be credible.
Is Germany a regional hegemon? According to Keohane (1986), the hegemon “must have access to crucial raw materials, control major source of capital, maintain a large market for imports, and hold comparative advantages in good with high value added, yielding relatively high wages and profits”. This definition is somewhat expansive. A weaker version requires the hegemonic state to be “powerful enough to maintain the essential rules governing interstate relations, and willing to do so” rather than “structural domination”. Germany does have access to raw materials, even though this access is taking place on a commercial rather than a political or jurisdictional basis. Depending on how narrowly one defines this characteristic, Germany may or may not meet it. It does however meet all the other criteria. Germany is undoubtedly the largest provider of capital in Europe. Its current account surplus (equivalent to net capital flows) is running at around 4-5% of GDP (or EUR 200 bn). It is also the largest producer of capital goods. Not only is Germany the largest economy in EMU, it is also the largest market of intra-EMU imports, accounting. Last but not least, it does hold a comparative advantage in terms of high value added goods and both wages are high and corporate sector is very profitable.
This definition of hegemony may be a somewhat arbitrary definition. Ultimately, it may be more interesting to analyse how, where and to what effect German economic power historically manifested itself. In economic terms, the breakdown of the Bretton Woods system left Germany’s macroeconomic preferences unchanged, while its own macroeconomic policies in the context of fixed exchange rate and increasing cross-border capital flows created increasing constraints for others. Germany’s power was largely structural in nature. While Germany had a strong preference for stabilizing intra-European exchange rate in order to maintain financial stability and export competitiveness, its ability to change other countries economic policy mix was very limited. Indirectly, however, structural power contributed to the decision of other countries to agree to so-called convergence policies and a German-style monetary union. 
European monetary integration has increased German power, but has also increased its vulnerability. EMU may or may not have been a quid pro quo for German reunification. But EMU almost completely reflected German policy preferences and effectively led to the extension of Germany’s monetary regime to the rest of Europe. EMU ended up increasing Germany’s relative power (as well as its absolute economic-financial vulnerability). Rising market pressures punished fiscally weaker countries, while enhancing the political power of the fiscally stronger countries, namely Germany. Germany’s ability to successfully operate under the constraints imposed by EMU (low inflation, no competitive devaluation, generation of growth via exports) combined with a domestically institutionalised preference for fiscal discipline allowed Germany to out-compete most other countries and maintain sound public finances. This ended up conferring relational power, defined as getting somebody to do something s/he would not otherwise have done. Not only does the newly emerging Eurozone governance structure, including the initial rescue efforts, reflect German preferences. 

Monday, May 20, 2013

Government debt in the advanced economies with special reference to Japan (2013)

Japan is the country with the highest level of government debt among the advanced economies. Continued large fiscal deficits will push the debt-to-GDP ratio to more than 250% of GDP by the middle of the present decade. Japan’s position is nonetheless not as dramatic as it looks. (1) In net terms (net of government financial assets), debt stands at 135% of GDP. This is still high, but not unprecedentedly so. (2) Government debt in Japan, unlike in the other advanced economies, is not consolidated on an intra-government basis. Intra-government consolidation would reduce the net debt ratio by another 20 percentage points or so. (3) If non-financial assets are taken into account (e.g. fixed assets, land), the government’s net worth is roughly zero. (4) Furthermore, if the government balance sheet is consolidated with the central bank and the broader public-sector, public sector net worth looks even more favourable. (5) Japanese government debt is predominantly owned by residents, predominantly banks. Government moral suasion makes it unlikely that they will refuse to finance the government. (6) Contingent liabilities in terms of future pension- health-related spending are comparatively low in Japan, in spite of relatively adverse demographic trends. (7) Last but not least, Japan is the world’s largest international creditor. Admittedly, if the government fails to significantly reduce the fiscal deficit of 9% of GDP (on a cyclically adjusted basis), government debt will become unsustainable over the medium- to long-term. Nonetheless: the Japanese government’s present financial stock position is not as dire as the headline figures might suggest.


Source: IMF

Tuesday, May 7, 2013

The political economy of structural reform in the BRIC (2013)

The BRIC economies, like most other economies in the world, experienced a slowdown in 2011-12. The bears are worrying that this slowdown might contain a significant structural component. These concerns seem somewhat overdone. Sure, the last decade saw strong global economic growth against a backdrop of low interest rates, increasing global trade flows, rising capital flows to emerging markets and rising commodity prices (the latter benefitting countries like Brazil and Russia). The global growth outlook for the next few years is more modest by comparison.

China is indeed unlikely to return to double-digit annual growth rates, not least because the authorities believe that 7-8% growth is sufficient to maintain political stability. Brazil continues to experience sub-par growth. Indian and Russian economic growth has also decelerated to multi-year-ex-2008/09 lows. The IMF has just revised its 2013 growth forecast to 3.4% and 5.7% for Russia and India, respectively, and 3% for Brazil.


Source: IMF

The growth potential of the BRIC economies nonetheless remains sizeable. All BRIC countries benefit from plenty of catch-up potential and scope to raise productivity via an increase in the physical and human capital stock. The first reason for optimism is that savings have not declined materially, and may even rise over the medium term. The current account positions are strong (China, Russia) or quite manageable (Brazil, India). This means that an acceleration of investment won’t be much constrained by a lack of savings.

Most importantly, the BRIC countries are economically well-positioned to unlock their growth potential through structural reform. Brazil and India, for instance, have taken a number of structural measures recently (e.g. greater FDI in India, infrastructure concession sales in Brazil) Rather than solely relying on anti-cyclical demand-oriented macro policies à la 2008/09, they seem to have been spurred into pursuing structural reform aimed at enhancing productivity and international competitiveness by concerns that the current slowdown might be more structural than cyclical. Admittedly, none of these reforms qualify as big-bang reforms; but they should, at the margin, help support growth over the medium term. Encouragingly, these measures reflect the authorities’ recognition that supply-side reforms are at least as necessary as demand-side policies if high growth is to be sustained over the longer term. Rising inflation in both countries has undoubtedly helped focus policy-makers’ minds.

China has thus far largely refrained from taking strong anti-cyclical policy measures as well as from pushing major structural reforms. This is largely explained by the leadership transition as well as concerns about the longer-term potential negative consequences another large policy stimulus might have for existing economic imbalances. Technocratic-minded groups have put forward a blueprint for further financial sector reform and analysts expect a number of other measures to be forthcoming under the new government (e.g. social housing, infrastructure). The recent publication of a plan to raise household income shows that the authorities are aware of the need to tweak the growth model. Russia is looking at a number of reforms following last year’s presidential elections; though, it remains to be seen how serious the new government is about reform. Importantly, the Russian government seeks to privatise USD 45 bn worth of public sector assets in 2013-15 and to increase infrastructure investment, especially in the Far East.

Recent Brazilian and Indian reforms may appear somewhat surprising. After all, the political-institutional backdrop for reform appears relatively unfavourable – more so in India than in Brazil. PM Singh’s government has been struggling for a long time to persuade its unruly parliamentary coalition to back reforms. The opposition BJP, though in principle more inclined toward reform, has proven less accommodative of reforms than might have been expected. Aggressive reforms carry the risk of destabilising the parliamentary coalition government. This is one of the main reasons why India has not seen more extensive reforms over and above the measures alluded to above.

In Brazil’s presidential political system, unlike in India, the executive does not depend on its congressional base for survival; but the president similarly needs to rally support in a highly fragmented congressional base and multiparty presidential coalitions in order to implement more wide-ranging reforms. The government has had at least one major success (e.g. public sector pension reform). It has also taken a number of other measures aimed at reviving economic growth (e.g. tax cuts, lowering of electricity tariffs). These latter measures did not require the president to spend lots of political capital or build large coalitions in congress, which perhaps explains why they were passed easily.

In institutional terms, the Chinese and Russian governments are better positioned to implement structural reform than Brazil and India, at least as far as the surmounting of legislative obstacles and societal opposition is concerned. In Russia, the presidency has not only extensive powers, but it currently also enjoys a majority in the Duma. In China, the executive rules supreme, even if it often has to contend with different technocratic and regional factions as well as well-connected vested interests, before a sufficiently large consensus on reform policies can be reached. In this respect, it is crucial that Chinese governments (or leadership groups) typically stay in power for a whole decade.

This latter fact is significant because it affects the incentives to pursue structural reform. This is critical, for the economic – and political - benefits stemming from structural reform typically materialise only over time, while the political and electoral (or legitimacy) costs typically materialise instantly. The OECD in a recent study finds that the full pay-off from structural reforms takes on average five years to materialise. This coincides almost exactly with the electoral cycle in democracies. It is easy to see why, unless a country is facing a severe crisis – like India in 1991, Russia in 1997 and Brazil in the early nineties – big-ticket reforms are rather uncommon. If they do take place, they almost inevitably take place early on in a government’s term and, not infrequently, get watered down by vested interests or blocked entirely by so-called ‘veto players’. Given how concentrated the costs of, and how dispersed the benefits from, reforms are (aka higher medium-term growth), vested interest find it relatively easy to mobilise against reform relative to the ‘silent majority’, who would benefit relatively less than vested interests.

A moderate, gradual slowdown in economic growth is harder to instrumentalise in terms of mobilising political support for structural reform – as opposed to an outright economic or financial crisis. This is why the reforms in Brazil and India may look somewhat surprising – then again, the reforms that were passed are not exactly the type of high-impact, growth-accelerating reforms that are needed to raise economic growth dramatically. In purely political-institutional terms, China and, somewhat less so, Russia would appear to be far better positioned to pursue medium-term growth-enhancing reform than Brazil and India – at least once the government makes up its mind.

The long and short of it is this: if the growth decline in the BRIC economies were to prove more pronounced than we currently anticipate and reveal itself to be more structural than we believe, we would expect greater reform efforts to come through, especially in China and Russia. The relative lack of reform in China and Russia was likely due to the perception that economic growth remains broadly satisfactory. (This perception is changing fast in Russia at the moment.) It is encouraging that the Brazilian and Indian governments have taken structural measures – however modest in the eyes of critics – aimed at raising the medium-term growth potential, instead of solely relying on politically less costly demand side measures (though Brazil at least has done this, too). The current sense of pessimism pervading analysts’ views of the BRIC therefore appears overdone. None of this is meant to suggest that structural reforms will be politically easy. The good news is that at least there is a, albeit varying, degree of recognition among the BRIC governments that such reforms are necessary. Once committed to reform, China and Russia will have an easier time implementing them than Brazil and India.