Friday, September 24, 2010

BRIC sovereign wealth funds - the wealth of governments (2010)

BRIC FX reserve accumulation continues apace. As far as the BRICs are concerned, FX reserve accumulation is increasingly difficult to justify in terms of risk insurance: all four BRIC governments are net foreign (currency) creditors. Even if private- sector debt is included, national balance sheets look strong as far as solvency and liquidity are concerned. The performance of the BRICs throughout the crisis has also demonstrated their resilience, if not in terms of growth, at least in terms of financial stability. FX reserve accumulation is therefore characterised by diminishing returns in terms of insurance and increasing financial opportunity costs and (quasi-)fiscal losses. BRIC (and often EM) FX reserve accumulation is being driven by objectives other than risk reduction and financial return, namely: limiting exchange-rate volatility and/or preventing exchange-rate appreciation. By setting up sovereign wealth funds (SWF) with the goal of investing excess reserves more aggressively, the BRIC (and several other EMs) implicitly acknowledge as much.

Unless a government runs a fiscal surplus, it (or the central bank) needs to issue interest-bearing debt equivalent to the amount of FX reserve accumulation if FX purchases are to be fully sterilised. Similarly, unless an economy runs a current account surplus, FX reserve accumulation needs to be financed by an increase in foreign liabilities, whether in the form of debt or equity. For much of the 2000s, Russia ran both a fiscal and a current account surplus. China registered a current account surplus only. Brazil and India, by contrast, were running twin deficits.

From a sovereign perspective, financial returns on FX reserves are determined by the on-shore/off-shore interest rate differential, valuation changes and exchange rate effects. First, to the extent that the BRIC central banks issue sterilisation instruments, they will tend to run a negative carry, that is, they pay a higher interest on their domestic liabilities than they receive on their foreign assets. (China proved to be an exception in this regard during parts of the 2000s.) Second, valuation gains from exchange rate-depreciation vary. However, given relatively low inflation and faster productivity growth in the BRICs, valuations gains will likely be more limited than in the past. (China is even likely to sustain significant losses on the back of seemingly inevitable nominal exchange-rate appreciation.) Third, valuation gains tend to be limited given that a significant share of FX reserve assets is typically invested in short-term, high- grade debt (e.g. Treasury bills). The financial return prospects are not much better from a country perspective1. Depending on the country, valuation losses may remain unrealised, but losses resulting from a negative carry represent an actual cost to the public sector.

While initially the (quasi-)fiscal losses can be justified by declining external risk premia (esp. Brazil and Russia), excess FX reserve accumulation is more difficult to justify. Especially in the case of Brazil and India, countries with high levels of domestic debt and high domestic interest rates, it would be preferable to limit excess FX reserve accumulation financed by domestic debt issuance, as it adds to upward pressure on domestic interest rates. Although generating returns on official assets is not the primary objective and the fiscal costs are not prohibitive, it does make sense to invest excess reserves more aggressively to generate higher returns. This is why three of the four BRIC governments have set up SWFs. They differ in important respects. India has been debating the creation of an USD 10 bn SWF2.

Russia is a textbook example of a resource-dependent economy. Running both current account and fiscal surpluses throughout much of the 2000s, it made a tremendous amount of sense to absorb external surpluses into FX reserves and use the fiscal surpluses to sterilise the purchases by depositing them into an oil stabilisation fund. Russia is highly dependent on the export of volatile, largely non-renewable commodities. So is the government, indirectly. Accumulating FX reserves makes sense from both a stabilisation (volatile revenues, Dutch disease) andsavings―(inter-temporal equity) point of view.

In 2008, the Oil Stabilisation Fund, created in 2004, was split into a Reserve Fund and National Welfare Fund. The former was capped at 10% of GDP and its purpose was to provide the government with funds to finance future fiscal deficits. The latter aims at inter-temporal savings, mainly to support future pension outlays. The Reserve Fund currently has USD 39 bn under management, down from its peak of USD 143 bn just before the global financial crisis in mid-2008. The Reserve Fund only invests in foreign government bonds. The National Welfare Fund is worth USD 86 bn. The Fund can invest in higher-risk assets, including domestic assets, such as loans to domestic banks. The future size of the funds will critically depend on future oil prices and government fiscal performance. However, it currently looks as if the Reserve Fund may be depleted by 2011 owing to persistent fiscal deficits.

Unlike Russia, China has been running large and persistent current account surpluses and, indeed, capital account surpluses, but for the most part small fiscal deficits. In combination with a relatively fixed exchange rate, the central bank had to absorb these surpluses in the form of FX reserves. Until 2007, SAFE was solely responsible for managing PBoC FX reserve holdings. That same year, the China Investment Corporation (CIC), which currently has about USD 300 bn worth of assets under management, was created3. The Chinese government controls a number of other agencies and institutions that manage foreign assets (e.g. African Development Fund, Chinese Development Bank, National Social Security Fund, (partially) state-controlled banks, SOEs). In China, more so than in other countries, it is difficult to draw the line between public-sector- and private-sector-controlled assets. Moreover, SAFE or, more precisely, the SAFE Investment Company is estimated to have invested USD 300-400 bn in the form of ―non-reserve‖ assets4. So the CIC is not the only government vehicle to invest its foreign holdings more aggressively.

The costs of holding very large FX reserves (> 50% of GDP) are relatively manageable given relatively low on-shore rates, partly resulting from domestic financial repression, and a low government debt burden. Furthermore, as the economy continues to grow at double-digit rates in dollar terms, the fiscal costs, as a share of GDP, will be quite manageable. In fact, during parts of the 2000s, the on- shore/off-shore interest rate differential was in China‘s favour. China is, however, quite sensitive to capital losses in case of RMB appreciation. Continued FX reserve (or SWF) accumulation will likely continue apace given prospects of continued very large current account surpluses and, absent further liberalisation of capital outflows, continued capital account surpluses.

Unlike China and Russia, but like India, Brazil has been running both fiscal and current account deficits (with the exception of very small surpluses during 2003-07). A capital account surplus and a current account close to balance allowed the central bank to accumulate badly needed FX reserves following the 2002 crisis. Given double-digit on-shore interest rates, however, the ―financing― of FX reserves results in a substantial ―negative carry―. Nominal exchange-rate appreciation over the past few years has not helped, either. While reserve accumulation was instrumental in lowering external risk premia, and possibly domestic risk premia, further FX reserve accumulation will keep domestic interest rates high by adding to the stock of domestic government liabilities.

The Fundo Soberano do Brasil (FSB) was created in 2008. The central bank resisted the transfer of FX reserves to the FSB. In addition to an initial bond issue, the FSB will be financed primarily by fiscal revenues exceeding the targeted primary surplus, though in principle assets can be accumulated via appropriations assigned in the budget. It affords the government a great deal of flexibility; hence initial (and recently confirmed) concerns among some analysts that the government might use the Fund to intervene in the FX market. The FSB is very small and manages USD 9 bn worth of assets. The investment mandate of the Fund is quite flexible.

The Brazilian SWF also differs from the Chinese and Russian funds in that it has so far accumulated LCY assets via excess revenues or domestic debt issuance rather than FCY assets. Unless it uses these revenues to purchase FCY, however, it effectively raises (expensive) domestic debt to finance LCY assets. Given the significant interest rate differential, it makes less sense financially for Brazil to accumulate excess foreign assets than in the other BRICs – even more so, should the Fund remain solely invested in LCY assets. However, should the recent oil discoveries lead to both external and fiscal surpluses, the FSB could turn into a genuine savings fund‖. Both the stabilisation and inter-generational equity argument would then apply.

Without a doubt, China is by far the most important international financial player among the BRICs. In terms of official FX reserves, China currently holds USD 2,500 bn, compared with less than USD 300 bn in both Brazil and India, and USD 450 bn in Russia. It also holds the largest excess reserves, whichever way these are calculated, except in terms of M2. But as long as the government maintains restrictions on capital outflows, the relatively large stock of M2 does not represent a serious contingent claim on FX reserves, even if a relatively inflexible exchange rate regime remains in place.

China will also continue to accumulate more FX reserves than the other BRIC combined for the foreseeable future. The rise in net foreign assets has been staggering. Even in terms of the size of SWF, the CIC and SAFE Investment Company alone control USD 600 bn, compared with the FSB's less than USD 10 bn and Russia‘s (declining) USD 150 bn. The precise domestic-foreign asset split is not precisely known in either case (as far as we can tell). But, undoubtedly, China is the BRIC country with the largest amount of foreign assets held in SWFs, especially if SAFE Investment Company positions are included. Growing, if gradual, financial integration of the BRICs leading to a greater two-way flow of capital will also contribute to BRIC gross foreign asset accumulation. Even where reserve accumulation is financed by running up foreign liabilities (Brazil, India), governments will see their financial influence enhanced.

Central banks, which continue to control the vast bulk of public- sector, and often total, foreign assets, generally do not have the same discretion in their investment decisions, nor the expertise to generate higher risk-adjusted returns on their foreign assets than SWFs. However, even with the establishment of an SWF, it will be difficult for governments to "break even" and currency appreciation will lead to capital losses (in LCY terms). The benefits of continued official asset accumulation are therefore negative from a narrow financial point of view. The economic benefits, less easy to quantify, may be significant (e.g. competitive exchange rate, attract knowledge- and technology-transferring FDI in the export sector), and the fiscal costs, while tangible, will remain manageable. A greater focus on financial returns in the management of BRIC government assets will help limit (quasi-) fiscal losses, but will not eliminate it.

Last but not least, the more excess reserves a government holds, the more flexibility it has in terms of when and where and at what conditions to invest them. This allows the government to deploy hard-currency loans and financing in the pursuit of both commercial and non-commercial (political) interests. For instance, governments can extend FCY loans to domestic companies, whether state- controlled or not, at below-market levels in pursuit of national objectives (e.g. China‘s “going global” policy). The government can also provide loans to governments in pursuit of political objectives (e.g. Moscow‘s loan offers to Belarus) or to foreign suppliers in support of long-term supply contracts, thus ensuring access to strategically important resources (e.g. China‘s oil-loan deals with Brazil, Venezuela etc.). These are all options that none of the BRICs came even close to having a decade ago. In short, the BRIC governments have become financial players to be reckoned with.



Wednesday, September 15, 2010

Why it is time for the (BR)ICs to further liberalise capital outflows (2010)

The degree of capital account openness is difficult to measure precisely. Different approaches yield different degrees of openness. Few analysts would disagree, however, that both Brazil and Russia have a more open capital account than China and India. The degree of capital account openness affects the composition and size of external balance sheets. In Russia, the sum of gross external liabilities and assets as a percentage of GDP amounts to 170% of GDP, compared with a 100% or less in the other BRIC. However, if reserve assets are excluded, both Brazil (84%) and Russia (135%) are financially more open than China (54%) and India (51%).

BRIC external holdings are skewed towards high-grade debt (reserve assets), more so in China and India than in Brazil and Russia, and equity liabilities feature prominently on the other side of the balance sheet. From a risk perspective, this is desirable, as equity liabilities represent contingent claims and reserve assets are under the direct control of the authorities. While this asset-liability mix has helped turn the BRIC into international creditors (excluding equity liabilities), it also created a “short equity/ long debt” position. In purely financial terms, this is not an attractive position to hold. 

First, the superior prospects for long-term BRIC growth should lead to tangible equity appreciation. Second, a combination of low-ish BRIC inflation and faster productivity growth should tend to lead to currency appreciation, resulting in capital losses on net FCY-denominated assets. Third, even if capital losses are excluded, the BRIC pay more on their net equity liabilities than they earn on their net foreign debt assets. Fourth, the BRIC governments – to the extent that they sterilise FX reserve accumulation related intervention by issuing (relative) high-interest rate domestic debt – will have put up with “negative carry”. Thus, the BRIC run a double “negative carry”.

This explains the desire to invest “excess” FX reserve holdings more aggressively with the help of sovereign wealth funds. The BRIC sit on more than sufficient FX reserves: external financing requirements are lower than FX reserves; the governments are significant net foreign (currency) creditors and total net external debt is close to zero or negative. However, even under the best of circumstances, the governments of Brazil, India, Russia (on account of their high on-shore interest rates) and even China (on account of medium-term nominal currency appreciation) will find it next to impossible to make a profit. It will be similarly difficult to overcome the “negative” carry stemming from the “short equity/ long debt” position.

This is where a greater liberalization of capital outflows might help. First, reducing the share of reserve assets in total foreign assets would limit sterilization costs for the public sector. Second, it would also tend to lead to higher returns, as the private sector is presumably better positioned to generate higher returns than the public sector.

The combination of capital account restrictions and FX reserve accumulation has resulted in a financially unfavourable asset-liability structure. The desire to ensure financial stability, attract growth-enhancing FDI, and, in some cases more than in others, support export-led economic growth and development explains why the BRIC are running – and are willing to run – a financial loss on their foreign position. The financial loss can be considered both an “insurance premium” and a “growth subsidy”.

Effectively, the BRIC governments hold sufficient foreign assets to “collateralise” private sector foreign borrowing. This is not an efficient way to leverage BRIC growth prospects. Obviously, policymakers value economic and financial stability more than generating financial returns. However, the financial opportunity costs of running a “short equity/ long debt” position will continue to increase as BRIC external balance sheets grow, as a share of GDP. Greater (selective) liberalization of capital outflows would help boost the financial returns on foreign assets by allowing the private sector to hold higher return foreign assets. In this context, greater exchange rate flexibility would naturally be desirable. Understandably, governments are somewhat reluctant to liberalise capital outflows, fearing increased volatility. However, in purely economic terms, the BRIC governments’ favourable net foreign position should limit both their “fear of floating” and the “fear of free(er) capital outflows”.

What are the prospects of further liberalization, particularly in China and India? In the case of China, substantial liberalization is unlikely to take place until greater exchange rate flexibility has been achieved. Greater currency flexibility will only happen if the authorities come to believe that the volatility it might cause will not impact economic, financial and political stability. India is somewhat better placed to further open its capital account due to a higher degree of exchange rate flexibility and due to a lower (perceived) dependence on export-led growth. The arguments in favour of liberalization notwithstanding, both countries will maintain a gradual approach to liberalization.

Financial return considerations remain of secondary (or tertiary) importance. However, sooner or later, further capital account liberalisation will take place. The liberalisation of capital flows - both outflows and inflows - would lead to considerable growth in cross-border flows and holdings, especially in the case of China and India. (In advanced economies, combined cross-border assets and liabilities as a percentage of GDP average more than 300%, compared with only 100% and 75% in China and India; and reserve assets typically make up only a small share of total assets.) Capital account liberalisation certainly carries some risks, as the past has shown. But the BRIC economies’ international financial positions are sufficiently solid to allow a greater liberalisation of capital outflows. It would certainly help boost the financial returns on the BRICs’ international financial position and limit the government’s costs of carrying FX reserves.